Administrative costs make up between 20 to 34% of health care expenditures, roughly 1-4% of GDP. Often characterized as wasteful, these costs are also spent on beneficial activities such as auditing claims for fraud, overbilling, or wasteful care, as well as enforcing compliance with managed care restrictions that limit access to costly providers, services, and drugs. Likewise, while increased efficiency could reduce administrative costs, their outright elimination would likely have deleterious effects.
This paper begins with the premise that bureaucracy has both costs and benefits. Managed care policies that restrict health care use trade off administrative burden for potential reductions in moral hazard1 and lower costs of insurance provision. The authors characterize this trade-off for prior authorization restrictions for prescription drugs, whereby patients can only receive insurance coverage for certain drugs (typically high-cost, on-patent drugs) if they receive explicit authorization; otherwise, they must pay the full cost out of pocket. Acquiring the necessary authorization requires the patient’s physician to fill out pre-specified paperwork to justify the drug’s prescription.
The goal of these policies is to restrict access to costly drugs to only those patients for whom those drugs provide the highest value. However, prior authorization comes with significant administrative costs: an average of 20.4 manpower hours per physician per week for physician practices in 2009; 34% of physicians report having at least one staff member who works exclusively on prior authorization requests.
That said, there are benefits to this process. Briefly, prior authorization allows providers to directly communicate information to insurers about the patient’s suitability for the drug, allowing insurers to target coverage denials to low-value use. Put another way, all of that paperwork signals the provider’s beliefs about a patient’s suitability for the drug. One imagines a doctor thinking: “I am not going through all of this hassle unless it is truly necessary.”
To examine this question and related issues, the authors study prior authorization empirically in Medicare Part D, the public drug insurance program for the elderly in the United States, focusing on the Low-Income Subsidy (LIS) program. The LIS program has two appealing features: First, LIS beneficiaries effectively pay nothing out of pocket for covered drugs, making prior authorization the primary feature of the insurance contract that shapes drug demand. Second, LIS beneficiaries frequently face default rules that assign them to a randomly chosen, and binding, plan if they do not make an active plan choice.
Please see the working paper for more details on the authors’ research design, but they begin by measuring the effect of prior authorization on drug utilization by comparing (within a given drug, region, and year) utilization for beneficiaries who are enrolled in plans that have authorization restrictions on that drug, against those assigned to plans that cover the drug without restriction, to find the following:
Bottom line: Prior authorization restrictions are a powerful tool for reducing health care costs. Though they generate substantial administrative costs, these costs are small relative to the reductions in drug spending achieved by the restrictions, and those costs are also decreasing over time. Additionally, this work suggests that the first-order effect of prior authorization is not wasteful spending on bureaucratic processes; instead, the first-order effects are on drug utilization.
The authors close with a rich discussion on the welfare effects of prior authorization restrictions, as well as implications for other policy options, and readers would do well to visit this section. One case in point: a better understanding of administrative costs could shed light on the relative merits of health care systems in the US (where non-price rationing is done through managed care policies that generate administrative costs) vs. other OECD countries (where queue-based systems generate costs by forcing people to wait).
1 Moral hazard occurs when an economic agent (e.g., a person, household, business) has an incentive to increase its exposure to risk because it does not bear the full costs of that risk. For example, a bank with fully insured deposits, or even implied insurance by a government’s too-big-to-fail policy, may take on higher risk knowing that those risks will be covered.