Recent proposals in the United States to increase the federal minimum wage from its current level of $7.25 (per hour) to at least $15 would impact a large fraction of the US workforce. About 40% of non-college-educated workers and 10% of college-educated workers currently earn a wage lower than $15. However, not all workers within those education groups would experience a wage increase in the same way. For example, as the accompanying figure illustrates, a $15 minimum wage would nearly double the wages of workers in the bottom 20% of the non-college wage distribution but would not bind on workers in the top 60%. The variation in wages within an education group is an order of magnitude larger than the variation in wages across education groups.

This substantial heterogeneity in wages raises an important question: What is the extent to which firms will substitute away from those workers who benefit from the large minimum wage? Existing research implies a low elasticity of substitution across workers in the short run; in other words, firms cannot quickly find other means of production (by, say, replacing humans with machines or replacing low-skilled workers with more productive workers) and therefore must pay workers the higher minimum wage. 

But the short run is not the whole story—a study of the distributional impact of the minimum wage across workers must distinguish between short- and long-run effects. The authors address this challenge by developing a framework to assess the distributional impact of the minimum wage over time. Broadly described, this novel framework includes features that reflect the effects of a minimum wage increase on the US economy in the short and long run, including a large sampling of jobs and a low degree of substitutability among inputs in the short run, as well as monopsony power in labor markets (or when one or a few firms face little competition for labor). Their main findings include:

  • A permanent increase in the minimum wage to $15 has beneficial effects on low-earning workers in the short run, when even a sizable increase in the minimum wage induces only a small adjustment in the employment of workers who initially earn less than the new minimum wage. Hence, an increase in the minimum wage leads to an increase in labor income and welfare for such workers.  
  • In the long run, though, firms slowly reorganize their production and start substituting away from such workers by, for example, gradually hiring more higher-skilled workers for whom the minimum wage does not bind and fewer of those for whom it does. 
  • The resulting welfare of such workers in response to large changes in the minimum wage needs to account for both the short-run benefits and the long-run costs. 
  • The authors show that other policies, such as an expansion of the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), which distributes funds to workers based on income and number of children, are more effective than the minimum wage in terms of helping lower-income workers in the long run.
  • All that said, there is a role for a minimum wage. The authors find that a modest minimum wage of about $9, which serves as a complement to the EITC, performs much better than either a minimum wage policy on its own, or an EITC policy on its own.

Bottom line for those hoping to improve the welfare of low-wage workers:  Combine a modest minimum wage with a progressive tax-transfer scheme, such as the EITC, as opposed to a large increase in the minimum wage that may prove beneficial in the short run, but that effectively prices workers out of the market in the long run. 

More on this topic

Research Briefs·Oct 2, 2024

Moving to Opportunity, Together

Seema Jayachandran, Lea Nassal, Matthew J. Notowidigdo, Marie Paul, Heather Sarsons, and Elin Sundberg
When heterosexual couples in Germany and Sweden relocate, men’s earnings increase by 5-10%, while women’s do not change. Couples are more likely to relocate when the man, rather than the woman, is laid off. These gaps appear at least in...
Topics: Employment & Wages
Research Briefs·Jul 18, 2024

Historical Differences in Female-Owned Manufacturing Establishments: The United States, 1850-1880

Ruveyda Gozen, Richard Hornbeck, Anders Humlum, and Martin Rotemberg
During the late 1800s, manufacturing establishments owned by females were smaller than those owned by males and had lower capital-to-output ratios. Female-owned establishments employed more women and paid women higher wages, and were concentrated in sub-industries like women’s clothing and...
Topics: Employment & Wages
Research Briefs·May 23, 2024

Can You Erase the Mark of a Criminal Record? Labor Market Impacts of Criminal Record Remediation

Amanda Y. Agan,  Andrew Garin, Dmitri K. Koustas, Alexandre Mas, and Crystal Yang
Removing a previously obtained criminal record does not improve labor market outcomes, on average, with the notable exception of participation in gig work through online platforms.
Topics: Economic Mobility & Poverty, Employment & Wages