Key Takeaways
  • Researchers have long studied unofficial revenue generation in weak states, but often with a focus on corruption by individuals in isolation from their system.
  • This pathbreaking research merges a large and unique dataset, along with qualitative interviews, to expose the influence of corruption systems organized by the state officials’ managers.
  • Importantly, the authors find that in a country with a weak state, systems of organized corruption with manager participation impose higher costs than would exist with individual corruption by individuals alone.

Given the dearth of data on what are, essentially, illegal activities amounting to corruption organized by managers within state agencies, researchers have been limited in their ability to examine this phenomenon. This novel research, though, draws on three years of empirical and qualitative work to investigate the economic organization of the real state in a specific agency—the traffic police agency of the Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC)’s capital Kinshasa in 2015—to study how officials organize unofficial revenue generation, to analyze what share of revenue is generated through such organization, and to determine whether its existence as a system creates social costs or benefits above those that would be created by independent unofficial practices. 

Their rich dataset allows the authors to ask a key question: In a weak state managed by agents who demand unofficial revenue, which form is worse—organized or independent illegal activities? The authors’ answer is clear: Organized corruption creates profits and distortions beyond those attainable by individual agents. This unprecedented work has implications beyond traffic management in Kinshasa, and offers insights for policymakers, planners, and researchers on the real operations of weak states throughout the world.  

It’s nothing personal, but I’ve got a quota to fill 

Before describing the authors’ methodology and findings, it is useful to understand the real state in Congo, at least as exemplified in Kinshasa’s branch of the traffic policy agency in 2015. The official dual mandate of the agency was to manage traffic flows to prevent congestion, and to issue official charges to drivers who violate the traffic code. Police commanders (or managers) at police stations deployed police officers (or agents) to the intersections in teams to manage traffic, and to escort drivers who violated the code to the police station, so that the managers could issue a charge. So far, so good. This sounds like any official traffic control effort. 

Unofficially, though, drivers paid bribes to the agents in the street through a system of toll fees to avoid being escorted, and to managers in the police station to avoid charges. These payments, or corruption, were considered unofficial revenue (i.e., they do not add to the public revenue of the state), in contrast to revenue from legitimate traffic fines, which was considered official (i.e., they do add to public revenue). Further, the method of unofficial fine revenue collection was not left to chance or the whimsy of agents; rather, unofficial revenue hinged on a “quota scheme” whereby managers ordered agents to escort a certain number of drivers each day to the police station so managers could directly extract bribes. Contributing to maximize the revenue generated by the system, managers also occasionally forged evidence when drivers had not made a clear violation, using this extortion to extract payments from drivers.

As for their methodology, the authors’ research is grounded on a large and unique dataset, including 13,254 police agent/driver interactions observed at intersections, 3,345 manager/driver interactions observed inside police stations, 2,997 hourly observations of traffic outcomes at intersections, and 327 team of agents-day quota level agreements, covering half of one of the two battalions of the traffic police agency with jurisdiction over half of Kinshasa. The authors also conducted many qualitative interviews.

To collect this dataset, the authors trained and worked with 160 individuals to implement six independent wide-casting research operations within the agency, allowing an unprecedented snapshot of the inner workings of a state agency in which corruption has spread through the hierarchy. This effort included recording all transactions between drivers and agents, the quota schemes, the details of all transactions that occurred inside police stations, the properties of public service in real time, and the schemes developed between managers and higher-level officials. To gather this data, they collaborated openly with some agency employees and surreptitiously recorded other conversations. Please see the full paper for more details on this extraordinary data-gathering effort.

Additional Material: Inside the Congo’s Traffic Police Agency

 

The authors’ empirical findings include the following:  

  • Each day, each police station requests 18.59 vehicles on average through the quota for each team of agents, and the agents escort 17.55 drivers on average. Of those, 11.06 drivers pay a bribe to managers on the same day, 1.84 pay a fine on the same day, and the remaining 5.65 resolve their case on a later day. 
  • The average bribe paid to a manager is 20.35 USD, while the average fine is 45.68 USD. 
  • 44% of 2,252 records with alleged infractions at the station involved accusations of committing an infraction verifiable by a third party (e.g., does not own a driving license), while 56% involved accusations of committing an unverifiable one (e.g., dangerous maneuver). 
  • 23% of the escorted drivers have a “protector,” or a high-ranked official whom the drivers call during the negotiation. Having a protector equals a 13 pp. (18%) lower propensity to pay a bribe in the station; a 9 USD (38%) lower level of the bribes; and a 5pp. (38%) lower propensity to pay a fine. Taxi drivers are three times less likely to have a protector than other drivers; they also pay the highest bribes.
  • Each station yields, on average, 2,995.30 USD of fine revenue every month, which is only 22% of total revenue: unofficially, each station yields on average 12,118.07 USD in bribe revenue monthly (the remaining 78% of total revenue), of which 4,450.88 (37%) is from bribes drivers pay in the street to the agents and 7,667.19 (63%) is from those they pay in the station to the managers. 
  • The mean unofficial income of a police station staff member was at least 2,572.11 USD monthly, i.e., 13 and 37 times the wage of a teacher, and of the manager, respectively, in 2015.

How socially costly is the component of corruption that is organized by managers?

On the one hand, it is intuitive to imagine that such a system has a social cost, by discouraging agents to manage traffic and instead fabricate allegations and escort drivers. On the other hand, the quota system may discourage drivers from violating the law to avoid paying a bribe or a fine. For example, if you know that the least infraction may result in you being hauled, often violently, to the police station to face a shake-down, you might drive more carefully. 

The method of unofficial fine revenue collection was not left to chance or the whimsy of agents; rather, unofficial revenue hinged on a “quota scheme” whereby managers ordered agents to escort a certain number of drivers each day to the police station so managers could directly extract bribes.

So, to derive the social cost from this organized form of corruption, the authors developed a randomized experiment where managers requested a quota that was, at most, half the mean level for that team of agents, on randomly selected days (the managers were compensated for their lack of unofficial revenue). This allowed the authors to compare public service under the current system vs. that with agent corruption alone. Spoiler alert: Decreasing the quota and, hence, mitigating its effect, the authors find that the quota worsens the agency’s ability to fulfill its first mandate (to manage traffic), while not improving its ability to fulfill the second (to enforce the traffic code). In particular, the authors find the following:

  • Because of the disruptive nature of traffic stops at intersections, the quota scheme causes close to all accidents and 65% of all traffic jams at the intersections, resulting in significant social cost. 
  • The quota scheme disproportionately induces agents to produce false allegations; a one-unit increase in the quota increases unverifiable infractions by six times more than that of verifiable ones. Further, open-ended answers by street observers describing the 13,254 driver-agent interactions reveals that quotas cause an increase in observed false allegations. Ultimately, in addition to its effect on traffic outcomes, the quota does not improve safety through  the effect it could have had on driver incentives to comply. 
  • The authors also find that managers use the quota scheme to create and maximize unofficial revenue with no increase in official fine revenue. 
  • Finally, reducing the quota level from its equilibrium level decreases total corruption revenue and does not lead to higher bribe collection by the agents, which the authors interpret as suggesting that the quota does not reflect contracting frictions between the manager and the agents. In other words, given that escorted drivers are unable to pay agents to avoid being escorted, the agency uses the quota to maximize corruption surplus.  

Bottom line: the unofficial quota system is socially costly, on net. 

CLOSING TAKEAWAY
Spoiler alert: Decreasing the quota and, hence, mitigating its effect, the authors find that the quota worsens the agency’s ability to fulfill its first mandate (to manage traffic), while not improving its ability to fulfill the second (to enforce the traffic code).

Conclusion

This unprecedented work offers a deep look into the real governance of an agency within a weak state, in this case the police traffic agency in Kinshasa, Congo, in 2015. This system of corruption involving managers generates significant revenue for the agency and directly worsens traffic outcomes, while it does not appear to incentivize drivers to comply with the driving code—additional arrests caused by the system are likely driven by false allegations. 

What lessons does this work hold for planners and policymakers looking to reduce the influence of corruption in weak states? One commonly suggested antidote to corruption is to pay traffic officers, in this case, a wage that exceeds their unofficial option: if the risk of detection and dismissal is sufficiently large, the officers could be deterred with a sufficiently high wage. However, if agents have more income, managers often demand a slice of the pie, by demanding a higher quota or even begin taking a cut of the agents’ income. 

Indeed, in ongoing research, the authors have determined that managers tax 30 percent of such income, but this taxation occurs almost only when the cash transfer produces inequality between teams of agents, consistent with the distribution of unofficial income being important in the preservation of the system. Managed corruption, in other words—once it is systematized in a weak state—appears difficult to unwind.

While it is common to note at the end of such briefings that more research is needed, and that is certainly true in this case, it is also important to acknowledge that future work will certainly be influenced by the pathbreaking insights of this research on real governance within weak states. For years, the literature has focused on the effects of independent illegal activity, but this work shines a bright light on the profits and distortions—including social cost—of organized corruption.

More on this topic

Research Briefs·Mar 22, 2024

Fallow Lengths and the Structure of Property Rights

Etienne Le Rossignol, Sara Lowes, and Eduardo Montero
Places where land needs to be fallowed for longer periods are more likely to have communal property rights, both historically and presently. World Bank land titling interventions are less effective in places with longer fallow requirements, and longer fallow periods...
Topics: Development Economics
Research Briefs·Mar 6, 2024

Fiscal Rules, Austerity in Public Administration, and Political Accountability: Evidence from a Natural Experiment in Colombia

Maria Carreri and Luis R. Martínez
Limitations to fiscal spending in Colombia reduced overspending on public administration without affecting public goods, better aligning spending with voters’ preferences.
Topics: Development Economics, Monetary Policy
Research Briefs·Nov 29, 2023

Nothing Gold Can Stay: Artisanal Mine Certifications and Conflict Dynamics in the Congo

Hans Christensen and Samuel Chang
Conflict-free certifications for artisanal mines are associated with a 9.4% (16.3%) reduction in armed group–initiated conflicts (fatalities) within a 10-km radius of gold mines. After certifications, there is no aggregate reduction in conflict intensity in Eastern DRC territories, and conflicts...
Topics: Development Economics