Key Takeaways
  • Labor’s share of US corporate-sector income (or value added) fell five percentage points vs. the share going to capital, from 62.9 percent to 57.9 percent, since about 1980.
  • This decline coincided with a striking rise in the share of business activity organized in “pass-through” form, where businesses are not taxed at the corporate level but where income passes through to owners and is taxed as individual income.
  • This analysis finds that the 5-percentage-point decline in the labor share is overstated by 32%.
  • The authors’ adjustments are concentrated among mid-market firms in services, magnifying the role of the manufacturing sector and superstar firms in driving the remaining decline in the labor share.

However, what if the make-up of that five percentage points isn’t so obvious? Whether income is categorized as capital or labor is, in large part, determined by the tax code. Over the last 35 years, the US tax code has changed such that some companies, especially mid-sized service firms, have shifted between distributing income to owners as capital or labor income depending on which is most beneficial in each tax regime. Either way, the work has not changed; the only difference is how compensation is reported as income. Given this phenomenon, what is the true meaning of those 5 percentage points? Does the 57.9 percent labor share reflect an accurate accounting of labor income?

These questions, among others, motivate this new research, which finds that changes in the tax code, beginning with the Tax Reform Act of 1986, initiated reallocation among firms over the following decades that accounts for about one-third of the 5 percentage point decline in labor’s share of corporate-sector income between 1978 and 2017. For policymakers and others concerned about income disparities, these and other findings highlight the important role of tax policy when measuring income shares. 

Chart
Figure 1: Adjusted Corporate-Sector Labor Shares (1978-2017)
Note: This Figure combines the authors’ S-corporation and partnership adjustments. Over the 1978-2017 period, the authors’ corporate labor share series after both adjustments shows a decline of 3.4 percentage points, 31.9% (1.6pp) smaller than the 5.0 percentage point decline in the raw Bureau of Economic Analysis data. Instead of the corporate labor share declining from 62.9% in 1978 to 57.9% in 2017, the authors’ adjusted labor share declined from 62.9% to 59.5% in 2017. See working paper for more details.

Just passing through

Before reviewing the authors’ findings and key lessons, a brief discussion of relevant US tax policy is in order. To begin, the decline in labor’s share of corporate-sector value added coincided with a striking rise in the share of business activity organized in “pass-through” form, where businesses are not taxed at the corporate level but where income passes through to owners and is taxed as individual income. As the authors show, these trends are related.

Why would growth of the pass-through sector, which now accounts for the majority of business income, matter for the corporate-sector labor share? The simple answer is taxes. Entrepreneurs have flexibility to characterize their income as labor payments or as profits and typically choose the label that minimizes taxes subject to the tax code.

Why would growth of the pass-through sector, which now accounts for the majority of business income, matter for the corporate-sector labor share? As suggested above, the simple answer is taxes. Entrepreneurs have flexibility to characterize their income as labor payments or as profits and typically choose the label that minimizes taxes subject to the tax code. In recent years, the pass-through label has been profitable for a growing number of firms. At the same time, the composition of corporate-sector firms has changed, with many labor-intensive firms—like accounting firms, law firms, and medical practices—now organized outside the corporate sector as tax-preferred partnerships. 

Things began to change following the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (TRA86), which lowered personal income tax rates substantially and raised the tax burden on (non-pass-through) C-corporations (or those entities taxed separately from their owners). As a result, by organizing in pass-through form, entrepreneurs avoided C-corporation taxes and benefited from lower effective tax rates. Subsequent changes in payroll taxation and in the legal treatment of pass-throughs raised the benefits and feasibility of adopting pass-through form, accelerating the pace of this sector’s growth.

Mini-Glossary
Corporate-sector value added: Value added reflects the value generated by producing goods and services as measured by national accounts. Corporate-sector value added includes S- and C-corporation entities, and limited liability corporations (LLCs) that elect S-corporation form, but excludes government and non-corporate business value added, which includes partnerships, unincorporated businesses, and LLCs that elect partnership form.

Pass-through income: Business entities that are not taxed at the business entity level pass the income through to the owners, who are taxed at the individual or owner level, typically sole proprietorships, S-corporations, and partnerships.

C-corporation: Any corporation taxed separately from its owners.

S-corporation: Business entities that pass corporate income, losses, credits, and deductions to shareholders, who are primarily individuals, to include on their tax forms.

Partnership: Business entities that pass corporate income, losses, credits, and deductions to partners, which can include individuals, non-profits, corporations, and foreign owners.

Superstar firm: Large entities driving sectoral productivity and concentration, including possibly outsized influence on labor markets.

The authors conduct a two-part analysis to quantify the contribution of the pass-through sector to the decline of the labor share. First, they reclassify a portion of S-corporation value added. Using data on 183,000 firms that switched from C-corporation to S-corporation between 2000 and 2012, the authors estimate that 1.22% of aggregate S-corporation sales can be recharacterized as labor payments. This behavior implies the decline in labor payments captures a reporting response, as owner-managers compensate themselves in the tax-preferred form of S-corporation profits. Had these firms remained C-corporations, owner-managers would have likely continued to pay themselves via labor income to avoid payout and corporate tax. Reclassifying 1.22% of aggregate S-corporation sales increases the corporate-sector labor share by 0.89 percentage points in 2017.

The authors’ second adjustment is to “reincorporate” partnership activity into the corporate sector. Since 1980, partnership net income has grown from 13% to 35% of total business profits. This rise occurred as the corporate sector in the national accounts shrank from 60% to 57% of GDP, and the noncorporate business sector, which includes partnership activity, grew from 14% to 17% of GDP. In addition, partnership activity comprises mainly financial, legal, and consulting services, which have higher labor shares than the businesses that have remained in corporate form. Treating these partnerships as C-corporations both reverses the recent decline of corporate-sector value added relative to GDP and increases the corporate-sector labor share by 0.79 percentage points in 2017.

Together, these two adjustments imply the 5-percentage-point decline in the labor share is overstated by 32%. The extent of understated labor income has grown over time in line with the pass-through sector’s expansion. In the 1990s, the growth of S-corporations accounts for most of this effect, whereas partnerships play a larger role in more recent years. 

Finally, as noted above, more than half of the adjustment comes from skilled service firms in capital-light industries, such as law firms, consultancies, doctors’, and dentists’ offices, and financial service firms such as hedge funds and private equity funds. Such medium-sized firms account for a disproportionate share of pass-through value added, while large, capital-intensive manufacturers are more prominent as C-corporations. After accounting for downward bias among mid-market service firms, what is the likely explanation for the decline in labor share? The authors’ analysis suggests a larger role for superstar firms (large entities driving sectoral productivity and concentration, including outsized influence on labor markets) and the manufacturing sector (where capital-intensive activity has replaced labor and offshoring has displaced labor) to drive the remaining decline in the labor share.

CLOSING TAKEAWAY
Medium-sized firms account for a disproportionate share of pass-through value added, while large, capital-intensive manufacturers are more prominent as C-corporations.

Conclusion

The authors draw several lessons from their analysis, including that 

  • the decline in labor share has occurred since the early 2000s;
  • the biggest firms contribute the largest share of the decline, reinforcing the role of superstar firms;
  • the rise of the skilled service sector has coincided with those firms’ tendency to elect pass-through form and optimize payments to owners in response to tax rates;
  • this analysis may be uniquely relevant for the United States, where the labor share has declined most dramatically and capital taxes have fallen more than labor taxes in comparison to other countries;
  • and this work complements recent studies on the effect of taxes on macroeconomic measurement, which is important because separating proper measurement from deeper economic forces is key to setting good tax policy.

This last point is especially salient for policymakers, especially if they hope to craft tax policy that addresses real—rather than perceived—changes in the capital and labor shares of economic activity. One implied policy response from this analysis is to harmonize taxes such that business owners would be disincentivized to change their firms’ tax structures in response to changes in policy. Case in point: Following the 2017 tax reform, firms once again face new incentives to select a tax-minimizing corporate form. As this research reveals, investigating future trends in the labor share will require a deeper understanding of the nuances of the tax code.

More on this topic

Research Briefs·Jun 29, 2023

The Value of Student Debt Relief and the Role of Administrative Barriers: Evidence from the Teacher Loan Forgiveness Program

Damon Jones, Brian Jacob, and Benjamin J. Keys
Neither eligibility for nor information about the Teacher Loan Forgiveness (TLF) program affect teachers’ employment decisions. Information increases application and TLF receipt rates for teachers who have already accrued the five years required to be eligible. In general, teachers appear...
Topics: Fiscal Studies, Higher Education & Workforce Training
Research Briefs·May 22, 2023

Judging Nudging: Understanding the Welfare Effects of Nudges Versus Taxes

John A. List, Matthias Rodemeier, Sutanuka Roy, and Gregory K. Sun
A combination of nudges and taxes always outperforms each policy in isolation; however, there is large variation in how much these combinations add to social welfare, reinforcing the importance of empirically quantifying welfare effects.
Topics: Fiscal Studies
Research Briefs·May 19, 2023

Debt Moratoria: Evidence from Student Loan Forbearance

Ching-Tse Chen, Michael Dinerstein, and Constantine Yannelis
Relative to borrowers who had to continue paying their loans, borrowers allowed to pause their payments sharply increased mortgage, auto, and credit card borrowing, with little effect on loan delinquencies.
Topics: Fiscal Studies, Higher Education & Workforce Training