High energy use is increasingly a feature of many technology processing industries, including quantum computing, artificial intelligence, natural language processing, and cryptocurrency mining (cryptomining). For example, data centers and Bitcoin mining alone consume 0.9% and 0.5% of global electricity, respectively.  

This electricity consumption results in what economists describe as externalities, or the costs and benefits of an activity to an uninvolved third party. In this case, intensive electricity use can cause two negative externalities. The first is the carbon emission resulting from electricity production of cryptomining, with recent studies estimating that global emissions from Bitcoin mining alone equal the emissions produced by Pakistan. 

This paper concerns a second, unstudied externality, the real effects of technology processing on local economies. What, for example, are the spillovers from cryptomining on households and small businesses? How does the interaction of supply and demand impact prices and delivery of electricity to homes and businesses? As we shall see below, cryptomining also has positive externalities in that cryptomines produce local tax revenues, raising questions for the authors about net costs and benefits.

Before describing the authors’ methodology and findings, a note about cryptomining, which is the clearing of payment transactions for certain decentralized blockchain-based payment systems called (proof-of-work) cryptocurrencies. Any person or firm can become a cryptominer, which means solving increasingly complex computational puzzles to verify the validity of transactions. This has led to an arms race among firms who run large cryptomines, essentially warehouses full of specialized computers, crunching numbers across the world. And the key point here is that these cryptomines need lots of electricity.

The authors analyze the negative externalities of the high electricity use of cryptomining through two channels: prices, and quantity rationing. In the first case, the authors study New York State, specifically Upstate NY, excluding New York City and Long Island, which was an early market for cryptomining in the United States due to its cold climate, cheap electricity, and proximity to large hydropower sources. The region’s grid operator employs a marginal supply pricing algorithm, whereby upward pressure on prices from demand gets passed to households and small businesses. The authors combine detailed data on these local electricity prices, electricity usage, and other economic outcomes with hand-collected data on the likely location of cryptominers, to analyze whether and how the use of electricity by cryptominers affects local communities. Their findings include the following:

  • When Bitcoin prices are high, the returns from cryptomining are higher in expectation since the reward to miners is paid in Bitcoins. Thus, a higher Bitcoin price increases the demand for electricity by cryptominers.
  • There is a statistically significant, negative price elasticity of demand for electricity by the local communities, meaning that as the price of electricity rises, demand falls. These higher prices also lead to larger surpluses for electricity producers.
  • There is a positive and significant effect of cryptomining on tax generation. Treated communities experience a relative increase in taxes per capita by $6 dollars compared to control communities when the price of Bitcoin increases by 100%. To put these numbers in perspective, the price of Bitcoin increased from about $600 in 2016 to $7,500 in 2018, which could have led to higher taxes per capita in cryptomining communities by about $70, or 14% of the average tax revenue per capita.
  • Cryptomining leads the average household and small business in New York to pay an extra $88 and $168 in their electricity bills per year, respectively. In aggregate, Upstate NY households and small businesses pay $204 million and $92 million more annually, respectively.
  • When accounting for the differential increase in government revenues, cryptomining towns in Upstate NY generate almost $40 million in additional government revenues, thus recovering about 14% of the losses. As a result, the authors estimate a net consumer surplus loss of $257 million in Upstate NY. 

As noted, the authors also study the negative externalities of the high electricity use of cryptomining through quantity rationing. To do so, the authors turn to China, which hosted 65-82% of the world’s cryptomining during the last decade before a ban in 2021. Other details aside, in a quantity rationing system, when total demand increases, prices do not adjust; rather, the electricity supply is rationed among locations to align with physical infrastructure. The authors study 52 inland China city-areas to find the following:

  • After cryptomining enters a city, local fixed asset investments decline annually by 19%, and wage levels decline by 10%, suggesting that cryptomining tends to crowd out other business uses of electricity. 
  • These results also suggest that the crowded-out industrial uses of electricity would have led to larger investments in the physical and human capital of the local economy in the years following the entry of cryptomining. To put a number on it: Cryptomining entry is associated with a statistically significant drop in local GDP of 8.2%. 
  • Taken together, these findings suggest that local economies could suffer as a result of crowding out in the electricity market. 

Bottom line: This paper presents novel empirical evidence of the real effects of cryptomining on local economies. For US policymakers, the optimal response is likely not to ban cryptomining, which would only shift the problem elsewhere and restrict any possible tax revenue gains. Rather, the more optimal response is likely the development of electricity pricing schemes or dynamic quotas that minimize the adverse impact on the local community.

More on this topic

Research Briefs·Nov 11, 2024

Carbon Burden

Lubos Pastor, Robert F. Stambaugh, and Lucian A. Taylor
The US corporate sector’s “carbon burden” (the present value of social costs of its future carbon emissions) is 131% of total corporate equity value; 77% of individual firms have carbon burdens exceeding their market capitalizations.
Topics: Energy & Environment
Podcast Oct 29, 2024

Economics Meets Ecology: The Huge Costs of Ecosystem Declines

Tess Vigeland and Eyal Frank
Bats are considered a natural pesticide. When they began to die out due to an invasive fungus, farmers turned to chemicals to control pests. The result, as Eyal Frank of the Harris School of Public Policy describes on this episode...
Topics: Energy & Environment
Research Briefs·Sep 27, 2024

Toward an Understanding of the Economics of Prosumers: Evidence from a Natural Field Experiment

John List, Ioannis C. Pragidis, and Michael K. Price
Nudging energy prosumers to conserve via a home energy report reduces their energy consumption, with significant variation across seasons and times of day. This suggests that prosumers both shift their energy use away from peak hours and conserve overall.
Topics: Energy & Environment