Administrative costs make up between 20 to 34% of health care expenditures, roughly 1-4% of GDP. Often characterized as wasteful, these costs are also spent on beneficial activities such as auditing claims for fraud, overbilling, or wasteful care, as well as enforcing compliance with managed care restrictions that limit access to costly providers, services, and drugs. Likewise, while increased efficiency could reduce administrative costs, their outright elimination would likely have deleterious effects. 

This paper begins with the premise that bureaucracy has both costs and benefits. Managed care policies that restrict health care use trade off administrative burden for potential reductions in moral hazard1 and lower costs of insurance provision. The authors characterize this trade-off for prior authorization restrictions for prescription drugs, whereby patients can only receive insurance coverage for certain drugs (typically high-cost, on-patent drugs) if they receive explicit authorization; otherwise, they must pay the full cost out of pocket. Acquiring the necessary authorization requires the patient’s physician to fill out pre-specified paperwork to justify the drug’s prescription. 

The goal of these policies is to restrict access to costly drugs to only those patients for whom those drugs provide the highest value. However, prior authorization comes with significant administrative costs: an average of 20.4 manpower hours per physician per week for physician practices in 2009; 34% of physicians report having at least one staff member who works exclusively on prior authorization requests.

That said, there are benefits to this process. Briefly, prior authorization allows providers to directly communicate information to insurers about the patient’s suitability for the drug, allowing insurers to target coverage denials to low-value use. Put another way, all of that paperwork signals the provider’s beliefs about a patient’s suitability for the drug. One imagines a doctor thinking: “I am not going through all of this hassle unless it is truly necessary.”

To examine this question and related issues, the authors study prior authorization empirically in Medicare Part D, the public drug insurance program for the elderly in the United States, focusing on the Low-Income Subsidy (LIS) program. The LIS program has two appealing features: First, LIS beneficiaries effectively pay nothing out of pocket for covered drugs, making prior authorization the primary feature of the insurance contract that shapes drug demand. Second, LIS beneficiaries frequently face default rules that assign them to a randomly chosen, and binding, plan if they do not make an active plan choice. 

Please see the working paper for more details on the authors’ research design, but they begin by measuring the effect of prior authorization on drug utilization by comparing (within a given drug, region, and year) utilization for beneficiaries who are enrolled in plans that have authorization restrictions on that drug, against those assigned to plans that cover the drug without restriction, to find the following:

  • Prior authorization restrictions reduce the use of focal drugs by 26.8%, with slightly larger relative effects among non-white and older patients, and smaller relative effects on drugs in high-benefit classes.
  • Accounting for substitution to other medications (roughly half of patients do so), the authors estimate that the status quo use of prior authorization policies reduced total drug spending by 3.6%, or $96 per beneficiary-year, while only generating approximately $10 in paperwork costs.
  • This reduction in spending is comprised of a $112 per beneficiary-year reduction in spending on restricted drugs and a $16 per beneficiary-year increase in spending on cheaper, unrestricted drugs.

Bottom line: Prior authorization restrictions are a powerful tool for reducing health care costs. Though they generate substantial administrative costs, these costs are small relative to the reductions in drug spending achieved by the restrictions, and those costs are also decreasing over time. Additionally, this work suggests that the first-order effect of prior authorization is not wasteful spending on bureaucratic processes; instead, the first-order effects are on drug utilization. 

The authors close with a rich discussion on the welfare effects of prior authorization restrictions, as well as implications for other policy options, and readers would do well to visit this section. One case in point: a better understanding of administrative costs could shed light on the relative merits of health care systems in the US (where non-price rationing is done through managed care policies that generate administrative costs) vs. other OECD countries (where queue-based systems generate costs by forcing people to wait). 


 1 Moral hazard occurs when an economic agent (e.g., a person, household, business) has an incentive to increase its exposure to risk because it does not bear the full costs of that risk. For example, a bank with fully insured deposits, or even implied insurance by a government’s too-big-to-fail policy, may take on higher risk knowing that those risks will be covered.

More on this topic

Podcasts episode·Feb 18, 2025

The Economics of Health Insurance: Denials, Pre-Authorizations, and Cost Control

Tess Vigeland, Zarek Brot-Goldberg, Joshua Gottlieb, and Maggie Shi
The ongoing debate over health insurance denials has only intensified in recent months. In this episode of The Pie, host Tess Vigeland unpacks the economic forces shaping the US healthcare system with economists from the University of Chicago’s Harris School...
Topics: Health care
Podcasts episode·Jan 21, 2025

Five Years Later: How COVID-19 Reshaped Our Economy and Lives

Tess Vigeland and Matthew J. Notowidigdo
It’s been five years since the COVID-19 pandemic transformed the world. In this episode of The Pie, Matt Notowidigdo, Professor at the Chicago Booth School of Business, explores the pandemic’s lasting effects on education, work, and daily life. Join us...
Topics: Health care
Podcasts episode·Nov 12, 2024

Deadly Prescriptions: What Happens When Doctors Compete for Patients

Tess Vigeland and Molly Schnell
When some US states allowed nurse practitioners to prescribe controlled substances without physician oversight, a serious unintended consequence took hold: Doctors found themselves competing with those nurses for patients. Molly Schnell, BFI Saieh Family Fellow and assistant professor at Northwestern...
Topics: Health care