Trade policies often create winners and losers within a society. For example, lowering tariffs on imports may benefit consumers by reducing prices, and harm domestic manufacturers by increasing competition. In this paper, the authors study trade policies to reveal the extent to which policymakers prioritize certain groups. 

 

 

The authors develop a model to measure the tradeoffs between different beneficiaries of trade policies. Their model accounts for differences in exposure to international trade across regions and industries, both directly through imports and exports as well as indirectly through exposure to trade that arises from domestic supply chains. They apply their model to US trade policy in 2017 and estimate the value society places on a dollar transferred across individuals from 50 states (plus Washington, DC), and 23 industries. They find the following:

  • Tariff policy in 2017 suggests that society assigns different values to the income of US individuals who are working in different industries and living in different states. A hypothetical $1 received by an individual at the 99th percentile of the authors’ estimates of social value is equivalent to $1.91 received by an individual at the 10th percentile. 
  • This variation is mostly driven by large differences between people working in different industries. Tariff policy in 2017 suggests that society values income received by individuals working in the Apparel, Textiles, and Metals industries 450% more than income received by the average US individual. 
  • Perhaps surprisingly, differences in social values across states only play a minor role in explaining 2017 tariff policy. Society appears to value income received by residents of Idaho, the state with the highest social weight, only 8% more than that received by residents of West Virginia, the state with the lowest social weight.
  • Thirty percent of the variation in 2017 tariffs  across different goods and trading partners appears motivated by redistribution, of which 27% of the variation appears aimed at benefitting particular industries directly, and 3% appears aimed at targeting particular states.
  • The monetary transfers associated with redistributive trade protection are large. Transitioning to a hypothetical US economy where everyone is valued equally would shift roughly $2,400 per worker each year from region-sector pairs at the top decile of the authors’ welfare weights to those at the bottom decile. 
  • The sectors that exhibit the most lobbying behavior are clear winners from redistributive trade protection. They receive almost $5,000 per worker annually through tariff protections, despite spending less than $100 per worker annually on lobbying. 

Trade policy is by no means the only policy tool available to governments seeking to help some of their constituents at the expense of others. Environmental policy, competition policy, and financial regulation are all areas to which the approach developed in the paper would be straightforward to apply. In all such cases, this analysis can offer a blueprint for identifying who the politically favored are and for evaluating the economic importance of the political favors they receive. 

More on this topic

Research Briefs·Jul 18, 2024

Historical Differences in Female-Owned Manufacturing Establishments: The United States, 1850-1880

Ruveyda Gozen, Richard Hornbeck, Anders Humlum, and Martin Rotemberg
During the late 1800s, manufacturing establishments owned by females were smaller than those owned by males and had lower capital-to-output ratios. Female-owned establishments employed more women and paid women higher wages, and were concentrated in sub-industries like women’s clothing and...
Topics: Employment & Wages
Research Briefs·May 23, 2024

Can You Erase the Mark of a Criminal Record? Labor Market Impacts of Criminal Record Remediation

Amanda Y. Agan,  Andrew Garin, Dmitri K. Koustas, Alexandre Mas, and Crystal Yang
Removing a previously obtained criminal record does not improve labor market outcomes, on average, with the notable exception of participation in gig work through online platforms.
Topics: Economic Mobility & Poverty, Employment & Wages
Interactive Research Briefs·May 14, 2024

Return to Office and the Tenure Distribution

Austin Wright, David Van Dijcke, and Florian Gunsilius
Return-to-office (RTO) mandates drive employees away from firms, with senior employees leaving at the highest rates, likely leading to significant human capital costs in terms of output, productivity, innovation, and competitiveness for the companies implementing strict RTO policies.
Topics: COVID-19, Employment & Wages