The value of firms to society involves more than direct returns to shareholders, employees, and consumers, but also includes externalities: A cost or benefit that affects a third party that is not directly involved in an economic activity. Externalities can be positive or negative, and they can be caused by production or consumption. , which can be positive (such as technological spillovers from R&D investment), or negative (such as environmental damage). Understanding the magnitude of externalities is important as they can influence such policies as regulations and taxes, as well as corporate issues like sustainability efforts and risk management practices. Consumers and investors also weigh externalities when considering their relationships with firms.
Economists have long considered the role of firms and their broader effects on an economy and society. Milton Friedman famously wrote in 1970 that the social responsibility of firms is to maximize market value. In that New York Times piece, Friedman quotes from his book, Capitalism and Freedom, to conclude that in a free society, “there is one and only one social responsibility of business—to use its resources and engage in activities designed to increase its profits so long as it stays within the rules of the game, which is to say, engages in open and free competition without deception or fraud.”
However, in a world with externalities, such a rigid position breaks down. A firm’s shareholders, for example, may have concerns beyond the bottom line to include social and ethical issues. For example, does a firm’s “activities designed to increase its profits” allow it to spew pollution into the environment? Do firm activities have a negative impact on a certain demographic, or within a particular geographic space? Conversely, could a firm increase certain social benefits by attenuating its profit-maximizing goals?
This paper attempts to quantify one externality of current import: damages from corporate emissions of greenhouse gases. Key to measuring this carbon externality is recognizing its future dimensions, namely that carbon emissions have consequences for many years, and that the future path of those enduring emissions are crucial in determining effects of climate change. The authors’ contribution is to quantify the carbon externality while incorporating the impact of future emissions.
To measure the magnitude of the carbon externality, the authors develop what they term a “carbon burden,” which they define as the present value: The value today of an amount of money in the future. If the appropriate interest rate is 10 percent, then the present value of $100 spent or earned one year from now is $100 divided by 1.10, which is about $91. of the social costs associated with its future greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Key to the carbon burden is the social cost of carbon (SCC), which is the dollar cost of societal damages resulting from the emission of one additional ton of carbon into the atmosphere. The authors carefully aggregate the US carbon burden, including future ramifications of such policies as the 2015 Paris Agreement: A legally binding international treaty on climate change, adopted by 196 parties at the UN Climate Change Conference (COP21) on Dec. 12, 2015. Its goal is to hold “the increase in the global average temperature to well below 2°C above pre-industrial levels,” and to pursue efforts “to limit the temperature increase to 1.5°C above pre-industrial levels.” , under which the US aims to reduce its emissions by at least 26% by 2025 and 50% by 2030 (relative to the 2005 level). They find the following:
While these carbon burden data point to corporations as the main culprit, the authors are clear that responsibility also extends to household and industrial demand, and politics (for example, some European countries rely more on nuclear energy, which does not emit carbon). Further, efforts to reduce firm output of carbon is complicated by the symbiotic relationships among firms and across industries. It is simplistic to hold utilities fully accountable for their direct emissions when demand from other sectors also drives those emissions. That said, accountability for carbon emitters is necessary; the trick is to get it right. Regulatory discrepancies abound among firms of different sizes, for example, and rules vary among states. At the same time, measurement issues persist. Future research into the risk profile of carbon emissions that fully captures externalities and improves upon measurement, as well as analysis of the most effective policies, is necessary for the United States to even approach its Paris commitments.